The Continuity of Inequity
In Idle Theory's ideal scheme of progress, strict equality is
maintained, and the idleness of all men rises equally with
technical and ethical and political innovation. In idle time,
humanity acts as it pleases. If it pleases some to trade in
luxuries and amusements of various kinds, there is no obstruction.
Aristocracy
But in practice, historically, there appears never to have been
equality. Instead human society was divided into a minority of rich
(idle) kings, emperors, and aristocrats on the one hand, and a greater
mass of toiling (busy) bondsmen, serfs, and slaves on the other.
The simplest explanation for this inequality is that the kings and
their aristocratic companions emerged from nomadic hunting groups which
used their military power to subject agricultural societies.
Forcing successful farming communities to pay taxes or tributes made
for an idler life than the earlier life of nomadic hunting - which may
have been becoming increasingly difficult if hunting had decimated
wildlife. Once the nomadic hunters had learned how to use their
military force to subject agricultural societies, the subjection of
such societies proceeded at pace.
The hunters-turned-overlords retained much of their previous culture.
They continued to hunt. They continued to eat meat.
They continued to feast. They rode horses.
Their ethical codes and education
continued to emphasize the courage, physical fitness, martial arts, and
discipline, which had been essential to a life of hunting large animals.
An armed minority of aristocrats and their soldiers was able to
maintain a far larger majority of disarmed farmers and manufacturers
in subjection. These subjects were forced, on pain of death or
punishment, to perform whatever work their masters demanded of them.
Within the aristocracy there was a command hierarchy which owed
its origins to the requirements of nomadic hunting life. At the
apex was the king - the hunt master -, and below him his lieutenants,
and below them the mass of soldiery. The king and his immediate
court were the most idle, and his lieutenants less idle, and the
soldiers still less idle. But all were more idle than the farming
communities which they held in subjection.
The subjection of farming societies probably brought an end to
agricultural and technical innovation. For to the extent that any
subject succeeded in increasing their idleness by some innovation,
to that extent were new burdens of work laid upon them by their
masters. There ceased to exist any motivation to innovate, and
farming methods and farming technology stagnated.
In this stagnant circumstance, the only way that anyone could
increase their idleness was at the expense of someone else.
Aristocratic societies could only increase their wealth by
imperialistic expansion. Aristocracy fought with aristocracy.
The victors earned the tax and tributes of an expanded kingdom,
which could support a larger aristocracy, and a larger army
for further imperialistic adventures. For the subject farmers,
it made little difference: one iron heel was exchanged for another.
What technological development there was consisted almost
entirely in military innovation - new weapons, new fortifications -.
Thus while farming technology remained static, military technology
continually evolved.
Trade
Among the least idle of the aristocratic freemen, trade offered
one way of increasing idleness. The enterprising trader would
visit other kingdoms, and buy there cheap what was plentiful in
that kingdom, and sell it dear in another where it was scarce.
If salt - used as a food preservative -
was cheap in one place, and dear in another, a trader in
salt could make a considerable profit by transporting salt from
one place to the other.
But this trade could only be conducted in the intervals of peace
between the wars which regularly erupted. During wars, trade would
be interrupted, and goods seized or stolen. Even in peacetime,
traders might require expensive military escorts to hold bandits
or pirates at bay while their goods were in transport, and this
cost of protection imposed a tariff on trade.
But the effect of trade, to make available useful tools
and materials in places where they had hitherto been largely
absent, in itself served to increase the idleness of those
kingdoms between whom the trade was conducted, and particularly
those of the trading classes. The result was the emergence of
a small and rich new class of traders.
Trade thus opened up another means, apart from military conquest,
by which a society could increase its idleness. But the interests
of the emerging class of traders was at odds with those of a
militaristic aristocracy. The traders required peace to conduct
their business, and the aristocracy required war to advance their
interests. A training in mathematics, in accounting, in languages,
in diplomacy, was more suitable for a trader than physical education
or martial arts. The trading community - the bourgeoisie - became
a separate culture within the lower ranks of aristocratic freemen.
The growth of trade, and the emergence of manufactures which
produced higher value goods, at lower costs, further served to
increase social idleness. But, as before, the growth of idleness
was one in which the idle class expanded relative to the whole
population. An expanding "middle class" appeared.
As trade began to overtake war as the principal means by which
a people might enrich itself, the values of the trading classes
began to take precedence over the aristocratic virtues.
The continuation of the development of new technologies and
industries appears always to have resulted in the expansion of
the class of idle persons and the reduction of the class of busy
persons, rather than a uniform increase in idleness across the
whole of society.
This suggests that the continuation of the process will result
in a smaller and smaller proportion of society being required
to work to provide the necessities of life for the rest.
And, in time, perhaps only one person, and he only working
part-time, will provide everything necessary.
But there is another characteristic of modern society which
acts to ensure that all are kept working:
The Obligatory Production of Luxuries.
In Idle Theory, anything is a necessity that increases human
idleness, and anything is a luxury which decreases idleness.
The distinction between the two is absolute as the distinction
between addition and subtraction, plus and minus.
The trend of industry, historically, has been that technology has
acted not to reduce work equally across society, but rather has
acted to reduce the numbers of people required to work full time
in any industry. Thus, in the past, the greater bulk of a nation's
population lived and worked on the land. But the effect of the
introduction of farming machinery was not to reduce the work of
this population, but allow it to be performed by far fewer numbers
of people. Thus now only a few people are needed to work full-time
to feed the remainder.
The remainder were not freed from work. Rather they lost
the income that their work had provided them, which was now
being performed by a few men with agricultural machinery.
They had to earn their living in some other way.
And increasingly, as the amount of
necessary work dwindled, a living could only be had by
making and selling luxuries. In a society where one man's work
can produce the food and shelter for ten men, the other nine
must sell luxuries and amusements of one kind or another to
earn that food and shelter. They have to sing for their supper.
Idleness-producing necessities are traded for idleness-consuming
luxuries. Everyone works as hard as before, but increasingly
they produce and sell luxuries instead of necessities.
Thus increased idleness is immediately converted into luxuries,
not by any choice of those made idle, but out of the necessity
to somehow purchase the necessities of life. In modern Western
society, wealth almost always consists not in any abundance of
idle time, but in an abundance of material comforts and pleasures.
This has led to a vast and forced expansion in the trade in
luxuries of every kind. Each house is decorated with carpets,
furniture, paintings, radios, TVs, stereos, computer games.
The shops are filled, not with food but with cuisine, not
with clothes but with couture, as well as books, music, holidays,
cameras, oriental clothes and fruits, perfume.
In addition, rather more hidden, there is the sale of sex,
of pornography, of drugs. And, driven by the requirement to sell
luxuries of one sort or other, the constant tendency must be for
these amusements to be ever more thrilling, exciting, addictive.
The goal of every luxury manufacturer must be for a clientele
who are as addicted to his products as they are to food, and
preferably addicted to his products alone.
Modern society is thus increasingly characterised by the
contradiction whereby it has become necessary to make the unnecessary.
Luxuries have taken on the character of necessities.
From one point of view, this apparently seamless transition from
an economics of necessity to an economics of luxury could be
regarded as wonderfully successful, in that it gives everyone
something to do, keeps everyone busy, while transforming their
activities from work into play. It fills the world with art,
literature, music, motion pictures, cuisine, couture,
cosmetics, perfume, jewellery, games, in an
ever-expanding range of delights and amusements.
But from another point of view, the same transition nullifies
the promise of technology to free men from work. Technology has
simply acted to shift toiling humanity from making and selling
necessities to making and selling luxuries. The work never stops.
The hands that once crafted useful knives and pots now shape
hairstyles and write novels. Men who once worked to create idle
time now work just as hard to kill those idle hours. Freedom
to choose has been replaced by a range of consumption choices.
A case can made that all the evils of the modern world grow
from the trade of luxuries for necessities. It is a trade that
keeps humanity working as hard, if not harder, than their
poverty-stricken ancestors.
It makes for a life of increasing uncertainty,
because while whoever trades in necessities can be sure of a sale,
the trader in music or hairstyles is forever the victim
of ever-shifting fashions. (The Beatles bankrupted any number of
crooners and hairdressers.) And where fickle fashion is at play,
whoever deals in fashion items must be forever guessing which way
its winds will blow next. And when food becomes cuisine, and
clothing becomes couture, and shelter becomes penthouse, even
necessities metamorphose into luxuries. The humble potato must
dress itself up as french fries, or cheese and onion crisps, or
something equally fanciful. Fashion effectively re-introduces
famine and drought into human life, as goods go unsold.
And given that the idleness generated by any new technologies
is immediately converted into work to produce more luxury consumer
goods, human society ceases to hold out the any prospect of relief
from toil. And with that the most profound and ancient despair of
humanity - that they would never see relief from toil - gathers new
strength. The promise of technology, and of reason, having failed, men
revert to irrational cults (which are themselves expensive luxuries),
and to the oblivion of alcohol and opium, the nirvanas of heroin
and Ecstacy, turning inward away from a world which works not for
their relief, but for their subjection.
And when honest labour begets only more labour, it is
only through crime that any leisure is to be had. And so crime,
ranging from theft to the most elaborate financial swindles,
multiplies, and criminals are admired.
And in this way, everything that men put together over centuries,
from morality to law, from political organization to industry, is
eroded and damaged and nullified.